In
the early medieval period nomadic herders travelled across huge territories
freely however access to land over time, while remaining communal became more formalized
and restricted. Genghis Khan (1162?-1227) granted land to his allies to
cement his political and military power. This allowed a Mongolian
nobility to control communal pastureland and they were able to tax herders.
Thus as in England, an essentially feudal system was introduced, with a
monarch, granting land to an elite who were rewarded for their loyalty and
extracted wealth from the wider population. The reintroduction of
Buddhism in 1586 was another important development. As in England the
church was a major owner of land and an important political and economic power.
The formalization of land rights under the Buddhist authority and the
system of patronage established by Genghis Khan accelerated with the Manchu
Qing dynasty occupation of Mongolia in 1691.
The occupiers drew up a legal code and rigidly divided up the land,
eventually creating a hundred military territories known as khoshuun. Herders
who had previously moved from one territory to another had to stick to the
territory within which they were born, showing allegiance to the ruler of such
territory (Fernandez-Gimenez 2006: 31).
After
Manchu rule ended their system of formal property rights continued however
transhumance with herders moving their animals seasonally was maintained. Yet herders had to remain in the same khoshuun
rather than ranging where they
liked throughout Mongolian territory. Gradually some privately
control campsites emerged but communal and nomadic ways of life continued.
The creation of a 20th century Mongolian Republic, at least briefly, led
to a return to more flexible and locally controlled property ownership as
in 1925 feudal and religious structures were abolished. The 20th
century saw the introduction of soviet style collectivism that peaked in 1959
with 99% of herders cemented into this system of state central control of
agriculture. Once again the freedom of
herders was restricted by a governing power. With the collapse of the Soviet Union, a market
orientated Mongolian Republic emerged which saw attempts to privatize land
holdings. In the 21st century a greater understanding of the benefits of
communal herding may be re-emerging. Yet with economic and political
change in Mongolia communing has diminished.
While commons still exist and nomadic herding continues the territory
used by herders has shrank, their control over their animals has been reduced, while
informal regulation has been increasingly replaced by formal legal control (Fernandez-Gimenez
2006: 33).
Mongolia shows also that commons while difficult to
eliminate totally or control centrally are affected by external political
events. Genghis Khan, Tibetan Buddhism,
Chinese invasion, the Soviet experience and market based policies encouraged by
bodies such as the World Bank have all shaped the commons, nonetheless despite formalization
and erosion the Mongolian pastoral commons remains. The anthropologist David Sneath (2007)
has stressed the libertarian nature of Mongolian society, arguing that central
control has remained relatively weak with herders enjoying a large measure of
independence throughout many centuries. It is interesting to note that intercommoning by
nomadic people is still a feature of life in Mongolia but was eliminated in England
perhaps as early as the medieval period.
David Sneath (2000) has also suggested that
religious values that predate Buddhism influenced attitudes to land in Mongolia
during much of its history. Herders believed that spirits known
as gazariinezed were the owners of the land rather than humans.
These spirits were treated as high dignitaries and were given offerings
in ceremonies known as oboo. Typically, the tsagaanluu or white dragon
had to be presented with white food such as dairy products and rice. Such
ceremonies were followed by sporting festivals that included wrestling
contests. Today communal use remains a hot political topic with the land
issue differentiating new liberal parties in Mongolia who seek land privatization
and more traditional and left opponents who oppose this. In Chinese
controlled Inner Mongolia, mining is displacing herders and indigenous people
causing conflict. The conflict between communal agricultural use of land
or hunting and the needs of high growth economies to extract metals, minerals
and fossil fuels is played out in many parts of the world.
No comments:
Post a Comment